It surprises many that local, small scale and artisanal fishing communities thrive under a well-designed
system of secure and equitably distributed access privileges. Yet these are the very fishermen for whom
catch shares first evolved. ‘Modern’ programs have roots in traditions of coastal communities who
found practical ways to reduce conflict and waste while fairly allocating and valuing finite resources.
Political economists and anthropologists like the late Nobel Laureate Elinor Ostrom have documented
their spontaneous emergence in diverse fisheries. Each is unique; all share certain patterns. These
include clearly defined boundaries, known rules, recognized tenure, self-imposed sanctions, customary
laws, internal exchanges.
Fiji’s fishing groups formed goligoi, self-organized and self-enforced tenure system still active today. Japan’s ainu organize native fisheries in ways that date to the feudal era. Spatial, territorial and place-based catch share systems evolved globally for the benefit of small scale fishermen from Chile to the Gulf of Maine to the lakeshores of Eastern Africa to the seashores of India.
These deep and wide examples of ancient practice ensure catch shares can build on a secure foundation
of tradition. They provide a better opportunity than top-down regulatory systems for equitable
distribution of access to fishery resources. Instead of rewarding those few blessed with capital, catch
shares hold opportunity for most stakeholders without. Indeed, smart and participatory catch share
design can – and already does – ensure equity for all by protecting and promoting certain small scale
constituents as part of the overriding program goal, right from the start.
Legitimate concerns about ‘fair’ allocation tend to be a legacy from the old broken regulatory system, in
which equity was lacking, and where small-scale local fishermen had to keep racing for a dwindling slice, of a shrinking supply base, against larger and faster vessels from a distant port. Under open access, Cape Cod’s hook and line fishermen were failing to compete with better equipped trawlers, but a secure and scientifically accountable quota created a sector cooperative: one that leveled the playing field.
Catch shares are more democratic. Collective management allocates privileges of, by, for, and within
communities as a way to redress past inequality. Hence under catch share programs, native Maori now
hold tenure over half of New Zealand’s fish ; remote Native Americans along the coast of our largest
State hold a fifth of all fish under catch shares in Alaska’s Community Development Quota.
Even quota trading rules often benefit small scale fishermen. Alaskans designed their catch share
exchanges for halibut and sablefish so that smaller-boat fishermen can purchase or lease shares from
exiting larger vessels at a fair price – but not vice versa. Other catch shares set aside quota for the
community, holding back shares as a social safety net for certain at risk fishermen as a buffer to build
local resilience to external climatic and market forces.
Rather than break with the past, catch shares embrace proven traditions, restoring what for centuries
has worked to benefit the indigenous experience of local fishermen with an equitable stake in the long
term value of their fishery. As with fish, so with the small scale families who fish them: what robust
health the rise of big, industrial global forces nearly eradicated, catch shares put firmly back into place.
Article courtesy of EDF.
Welcome to Through the Gaps, the UK fishing industry's most comprehensive information and image resource. Newlyn is England's largest fish market and where over 50 species are regularly landed from handline, trawl, net, ring net and pot vessels including #MSC Certified #Hake, #Cornish Sardine, handlined bass, pollack and mackerel. Art work, graphics and digital fishing industry images available from stock or on commission.